The Foothills of Fed Firming
Opening remarks by Fed chair Janet Yellen at the annual Economic Symposium offered a clear glimpse of the foothills of Fed firming.
Vincent Reinhart
Chief Economist
The Foothills of
Fed Firming
August 30, 2016
Part of the attraction of attending the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City’s annual
Economic Symposium is the outstanding vista of the Grand Teton Mountains, right at your
doorstep. At this year’s event, however, five long-burning fires around the area obscured
the fine views and closed the southern entrance to Yellowstone National Park. On occasion,
though, the haze parted. The same could be said for the economic symposium itself, which
was mostly devoted to implementing monetary policy in a post-crisis world. This discussion
revolved around the mechanics of the money market and the appropriate size of a central
bank’s balance sheet, thereby shrouding the conference room in a thick blanket of technical
smoke.
The opening remarks by Chair Yellen, however, offered a clear glimpse of the foothills of Fed
firming. As we have noted before, the operative model of Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) functioning is one of delay at the top. Tightening has to be extracted from the
reluctant chair by the rest of her restive committee. Yellen accedes, on occasion, because
showing a willingness to tighten keeps her colleagues at bay. We believe the delay,
however, will keep the funds rate lower for longer.
In the weeks after the July meeting, we heard stirrings from FOMC participants, importantly
including Presidents Dudley and Williams and Vice Chair Fischer, that the widespread view
in markets that no action would be forthcoming in 2016 was puzzling. This assertion was
supported by a trip down memory lane. In the early summer, they had expected that
economy growth above trend would work down resource slack and push inflation up
toward their target of 2 percent. As a result, all of them anticipated tightening at least once
this year. The dismal nonfarm payrolls report for May and the unexpected UK referendum
result shook that collective confidence. In the event, the US economy and global financial
markets proved resilient. Indeed, the outlook was back on the track they expected in June
when they also expected to tighten this year.
Chair Yellen took ownership of this consensus view in Jackson Hole, reasoning:
“
In light of the continued solid performance of the labor market and our outlook for
economic activity and inflation, I believe the case for an increase in the federal funds rate has
strengthened in recent months.”
1
There were caveats. There are always the caveats that this was a forecast, not a promise,
and all decisions are data dependent and made meeting by meeting. But it was her
assessment, not a third-person attribution to most FOMC members.
This does put the September meeting in play, in a data-dependent sort of way. A solid
employment report in the neighborhood of June and July that put net job creation over the
latest three month at three-quarters million workers would make it hard for Fed officials
to wriggle out of their characterization that the pieces were in place to remove some
policy accommodation. They might still try to get off the hook, and an opportunity to do
so was offered during the rest of the symposium discussing the nuts and bolts of policy
implementation. Particular focus was directed on the wedges opening up across short-term
interest rates because of regulation and what that means for the pass through of policy action
to money market rates. These concerns may be especially salient at the FOMC September
meeting, given the shift in short-term funding patterns and pricing already in motion in
advance of the SEC requirement coming into force on October 14th that prime money market
mutual funds move to a floating net asset value and put up gates for investor withdrawals.
1
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20160826a.htm, accessed August 27, 2016.
2
In the two-out-of-
three case that July
employment gains
fall short of 225,000
workers and policy
stays on hold, the
FOMC will send
the strong signal of
action in December.
In the two-out-of-three case that July employment gains fall short of 225,000 workers and policy
stays on hold, the FOMC will send the strong signal of action in December by releasing a dot chart
that shows virtually all participants anticipating one tightening in 2016.
2
In any event, more of
the dots at the far right of the chart depicting the long-run nominal funds rate will cluster below 3
percent, conveying that this will be an extremely gradual rate renormalization.
What of the nonfarm payrolls report to be released September 2nd? Some high-frequency reading
on the economy were mixed, but initial claims for unemployment insurance in the employment
report survey week came in at only 252,000 new claimants. As the scatterplot below depicts, claims
in such a low range have been associated with strong net payroll gains since 2010.
The association is somewhat deceiving, however, because quits have trended up over the period,
implying that there are now fewer new eligible claimants for unemployment insurance at the same
level of labor market tautness than earlier in the sample. The dashed line at the right shows the
forecast of monthly net payroll gains as explained by initial claims in the survey week and a time
trend. The point forecast for July, around 190,000, is probably not quite hot enough to trigger
FOMC action. In the Standish judgmental forecast, we nudge this lower, to 175,000, in light of the
past few weak August readings and some giveback after two strong months. But jaggedness of the
actual outcomes compared with the predictions cautions that there is a plausible probability (say,
one-out-of-three) on a payroll number that is strong enough to trigger a rate hike in September.
After Chair Yellen’s opening remarks, the proceedings settled into a discussion of policy
implementation, or should the Fed’s balance sheet stay big forever?
3
As shown in the chart below
after successive rounds of quantitative easing, the Fed’s footprint in finance topped out at $4-1/2
trillion of assets, or just under one-quarter of nominal GDP.
2
If this reminds you of this time last year, it should.
3
The academic papers presented at the symposium can be found at https://www.kansascityfed.org/publications/research/escp/
symposiums/escp-2016
Labor market indicators, 2010 to 2016 (monthly)
Changes in nonfarm payrolls and initial claim
s
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, accessed via FRED and Standish calculations as of August 26, 2016
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
Jan-10
Oct-10
Jul-11
Apr-12
Jan-13
Oct-13
Jul-14
Apr-15
Jan-16
Predicted change based on
claims
Change in NFPs
-200
-100
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
0
200
400
600
Changein payrollss (1000s)
Initial claims in survey week (1000s)
Federal Reserve's Financial Asset
s
Source: Federal Reserve, Financial accounts of the U.S. as of August 29, 2016
$0
$500,000,000,000
$1,000,000,000,000
$1,500,000,000,000
$2,000,000,000,000
$2,500,000,000,000
$3,000,000,000,000
$3,500,000,000,000
$4,000,000,000,000
$4,500,000,000,000
$5,000,000,000,000
1945Q4
1954Q4
1963Q4
1972Q4
1981Q4
1990Q4
1999Q4
2008Q4
3
This additional
instrument to the
policy rate might
allow the Fed to
manage two goals—
price stability and
financial stability—
more effectively.
As balance sheets must balance, a large stock of assets also implies a large stock of liabilities,
offering pitfalls and opportunities in policy making on both sides of the ledger. My sense of the
bottom line listening to the discussions at Jackson Hole is that most—but decidedly not all—Fed
officials have learned to love a big balance sheet. Do not expect them to stop rolling over maturing
and prepaying securities anytime soon.
Why the support for something so as variance with the status quo ante bellum? A large stock
of assets gives them the option to adjust its composition so as to influence financial conditions
(think of the Maturity Extension Program redux or run in reverse). This additional instrument to the
policy rate might allow the Fed to manage two goals—price stability and financial stability—more
effectively. For instance, if officials were concerned about overheating in the housing market, they
could slow reinvestment (or sell outright) holding of mortgage backed securities and shorten the
average maturity of its Treasury securities without having to touch the fed funds rate.
The Fed, of course, will need a comparable volume of liabilities to fund those assets. The future
seems to be one in which those liabilities sit as reserves during the day, providing lubricant to the
funds transfer and clearing and settlement systems.
4
The Fed could drain a substantial fraction
of those reserves by the close of business through its reverse repurchase facility. That standing
facility provides as open, electronic auction of a super-safe asset—a loan to the Federal Reserve
collateralized by government securities—that fill a market gap. After all, regulation has significantly
expanded the demand for safe assets (as in the change the rules for money market mutual
funds) and made more costly the intermediation of them by banks (as in higher capital and the
supplementary leverage and liquidity coverage requirements). The New York Fed could arrange a
large rolling book of reverse RPs at varying maturities to provide a term structure of safe assets and
drain enough reserves to keep private market functioning of the reserve market active. In principle,
then, the FOMC could define the front end of the yield curve by setting the fixed rates on the reverse
RPs, perhaps even switching its formal target from the effective funds rate to these fixed rates.
For some in the room, all this sounded too good to be true. The future envisaged by the big-balance-
sheet lovers, it was feared, poses political risks and a permanently enlarged role for the Fed in finance.
In particular, a large stock of government assets pulls down Treasury funding costs and encourages
fiscal indiscipline. Moreover, holding that pot of bills, notes, and bonds might put the Fed in the
political crosshairs of a forced debt conversion at some later date. This risk might not be worth the
effort, especially if the efficacy of twists and turns in the composition of the portfolio were doubted.
As for the liability side, continuing to have a large volume of reserves outstanding will further
erode the functioning of the private market for reserves—the Fed funds markets—implying that its
effective rate will cease to be an accurate barometer of money market conditions. True, the reverse
RP facility can drain reserves, but given the enormous demand for safe assets, that may require very
large routine operations on a scale not imagined by the Fed founders.
As for financial stability, the presence of the super-safe asset may make investors quicker to run
from private alternatives at the first whiff of stress. And those first whiffs of stress might be harder
to detect if private activity at the front end of the yield curve is partly supplanted by official activity.
For now, all these issues are in play, as no note of urgency was voiced. They are also complicated.
But they also could redirect financial flows to the tune of trillions of dollars and change reference
rates. With the renormalization of the Fed’s interest rate policy stretching far into the future,
changes in balance-sheet policy seem even more remote. That provides time to study, and a cheat
sheet is provided below to help.
The Pros and Cons Of a Large Federal Reserve Balance Sheet
Assets
Liabilities
Advantages
•
Shifts in the composition of the
portfolio provide an additional
policy instrument.
•
A large stock of reserves keeps the
payments system lubricated.
•
Large volumes of daily reverse RPs
provide a safe asset.
Disadvantages
• Fine-tuning through portfolio
changes may be ineffective.
• Holding a large stock of assets
invites political interference.
• As the major participant in the money
market, the Fed overwrites price signals.
•
The private market for reserve may dry
up, rendering the effective funds rate an
unreliable indicator.
4
A comprehensive summary of this issue is offered in an FRBNY Staff Report by James McAndrews and Alexander Kroeger, “The Payment
System Benefits of High Reserve Balances” (June 2016), at https://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr779.
4
The comments provided herein are a general market overview and do not constitute investment advice, are not predictive of any future market performance, are not
provided as a sales or advertising communication, and do not represent an offer to sell or a solicitation of an offer to buy any security. Similarly, this information is not
intended to provide specific advice, recommendations or projected returns of any particular product of Standish Mellon Asset Management Company LLC (Standish). These
views are current as of the date of this communication and are subject to rapid change as economic and market conditions dictate. Though these views may be informed
by information from publicly available sources that we believe to be accurate, we can make no representation as to the accuracy of such sources nor the completeness of
such information. Please contact Standish for current information about our views of the economy and the markets. Portfolio composition is subject to change, and past
performance is no indication of future performance.
BNY Mellon is one of the world’s leading asset management organizations, encompassing BNY Mellon’s affiliated investment management firms, wealth management
services and global distribution companies. BNY Mellon is the corporate brand for The Bank of New York Mellon Corporation. Standish is a registered investment adviser and
BNY Mellon subsidiary.
WP/8-30-16/BR
Standish Mellon Asset Management Company LLC
Boston
• Pittsburgh
• San Francisco
Standish Mellon Asset Management (UK) Limited
London
www.standish.com
• info@standish.com
Previous
Next
More from Standish Mellon Asset Management
The most important insight of the day
Get the Harvest Daily Digest newsletter.